To
see LSGIs as being uncontaminated by class-struggle
would be an idealistic error, reminiscent of the old
"village community" hypothesis of Baden
Powell. They contain class contradictions, and the
mode of use of resources devolved to them under the
decentralization agenda occurs via class struggle
(whose intensity however varies depending on the degree
of antagonism that is immanent in the class configuration).
But even if there was no decentralization and the
mode of use of plan resources for these particular
items was bureaucratically determined, then the outcome
would still have been determined by class struggle,
but class struggle over shaping bureaucratic preference.
In short, decentralization neither does away with,
nor engenders, class-struggle in the countryside which
exists anyway and is a fact of life.
The impact of decentralization on this pre-existing
fact of life can be three-fold. First, it provides
an opportunity to the rural poor to assert themselves
in a way that bureaucratic decision-making would not
have made possible. True, the bureaucratic outcome
may turn out in many instances to be more "humane",
but it leaves no scope for the rural poor to realize
their subjectivity in this domain. For this very reason,
however, the need for organizing the rural poor to
assert themselves becomes paramount, and this need
can be fulfilled only through the intervention of
a political Party. The idea of Party-less LSGIs in
other words represents a throwback to the idealism
of the "village community" concept. This
greater ability on the part of the rural poor to assert
themselves would necessarily come into conflict with
the prevailing property relations in the countryside
(except in situations where radical land redistribution
has already been carried out), but that only underscores
the fact that "decentralization" is a part
of the dialectics of class struggle. It is not some
"ideal" arrangement at which society can
remain frozen, but part of the process of carrying
forward the dialectics of class struggle, which does
not necessarily mean of course a state of continuous
violent conflict. (In fact, the organization of the
rural poor by a political Party committed to their
emancipation is a means of controlling violent conflict).
Secondly, it provides a legacy for the construction
of a better society. Any socialist society must build
on the institutions bequeathed to it by the pre-existing
society. Indeed a part of the reason for the excessive
centralization, and the accompanying authoritarianism,
that prevailed in the earlier socialist societies
lay in the absence of any representative democratic
institutions in these societies prior to the emergence
of socialism on which the latter could build its foundations.
In that sense the decentralization experiment, by
empowering elected bodies, puts life into a whole
range of institutions on the basis of which a future
society can be built.
This argument must be sharply distinguished from the
so-called “social capital” argument. First, we are
talking here of representative political institutions,
not clubs or addas, or religious gatherings, or the
innumerable instances of social interaction among
individuals that the so-called “social capital” theory
picks up for celebration. The flourishing of such
instances of social interaction is not only perfectly
compatible with the putting in place of thoroughly
non-representative political institutions, but has
actually accompanied, throughout the history of modern
India, the most bizarre attempts at the denial of
political rights to large masses of the people. And
secondly, we are talking about representative political
institutions through which the conflict between classes
plays itself out, not about institutions sans such
conflict, and hence about institutions defending the
status quo, which typically constitute the desideratum
of “Social Capital” theory.
Thirdly, it trains the people in the art of book-keeping,
in the art of responsible financial management etc.
which constitutes another legacy for the future, apart
from strengthening even the existing system of parliamentary
democracy. One of the weaknesses of revolutionary
Russia that Lenin had highlighted was the absence
of knowledge of "bourgeois management principles".
The overcoming of this absence, even partially, would
go a long way towards providing the basis for the
construction of a socialist society in the future.
While there is no conflict between the perspective
of class struggle leading to the creation of a socialist
society and the empowerment of the LSGIs within our
prevailing social order through greater devolution
of resources (just as there is no conflict between
such devolution and the erection of a planned economy),
the opposite error can also be committed, namely the
the mistake of treating the LSGIs as if they already
constitute the organs of popular rule. There is an
ocean of difference between LSGIs within a bourgeois-landlord
order and "communes" in a socialist order.
While the latter can be built, looking at the matter
in very general terms, on the foundations provided
by the former, the vast gulf between the two must
not be overlooked.
Let me now come to the difference between Kerala-style
"decentralized planning" and the imperialist
concept of decentralization. This latter has no theoretical
basis, and hence is different from any of the four
senses in which the term has been used in economic
literature, to which reference was made earlier. Indeed,
it is never explicitly set out as one coherent vision;
on the contrary, there is a certain (deliberate) fuzziness
about it which allows it to mean all things to all
people[4] . One therefore
has to cull out the main features of this concept
of decentralization not so much from theoretical writings
on the subject as from the practices enforced on particular
State governments, such as Andhra Pradesh, which have
accepted the tutelage of imperialist agencies. There
is also an additional problem, namely there are different
imperialist agencies lording over different States
and over different sectors, which may make generalizations
difficult. We can discern nonetheless a degree of
consensus among them over conceptual issues, on the
basis of which we can reconstruct the imperialist
concept of decentralization.
This consensus arises above all from the fact that
all of them see “decentralization”, even in the sense
of devolution of powers and resources to lower tiers
of administration, as an aid to a “free-market” economy.
For instance, the World Bank puts forward its fuzzy
views on decentralization in a section of the World
Development Report 2002 which is titled Building Institutions
for Markets. In other words, “decentralization” for
imperialist agencies is not a matter of relocating
powers, resources and functions within an activist
State (in matters of investment), but of building
an apparatus that fits into the “neo-liberal” paradigm.
It is not surprising in this context that the following
four propositions regarding decentralization are more
or less common to all the imperialist agencies. First,
while they talk about Gram Sabhas they invariably
see the Gram Sabhas as being presided over, and led
by, not the elected representatives of the people,
but by outside officials. Their perspective in short
is not one of strengthening representative institutions
in the countryside, but of providing a democratic
veneer to a process of essentially bureaucratic decision-making
(which can always be manipulated to fall in line with
their wishes). Secondly, they see the major tasks
of the LSGIs being carried out through a number of
Committees, consisting not of elected representatives
of the people but of “experts” and corporate-NGOs,
and these are to be allowed to enter into direct negotiations
with funding agencies for loans for particular projects.
Thirdly, their emphasis is on “Self-Help” groups rather
than the “Right” of the LSGIs to a share of the Plan
funds of the State government. To be sure, Self-Help
groups can be of assistance to the rural poor under
certain circumstances, but what is noteworthy about
the perspective of these agencies is the overwhelming
emphasis on these groups to the exclusion of the LSGIs’
“Right” to Plan Funds. And finally, whenever any infrastructure
projects are undertaken at the local level, these
agencies insist on the imposition of “user charges”,
i.e. their exclusive emphasis is on the adoption of
the commercial principle even in the matter of peoples’
access to basic amenities.
What these four propositions amount to is a negation
of representative institutions, a negation of all
political activity, reflective of class struggle in
the countryside, in local government, a negation of
“Rights” of the people to Plan Funds as users of infrastructure,
and the erection of a mai-baap ethos, reminiscent
of the old colonial administration trying to wear
a paternalist cloak, with imperialist-aided NGOs being
presented as the benevolent patrons of the countryside.
In short, this concept of “decentralization” visualizes
a substitution of the State by a set of NGOs in the
implementation of local projects, including especially
social sector projects, the funds for which, whether
drawn from the State budget or from foreign donors,
are expended through these NGOs. Putting it differently,
imperialist "decentralization" is concerned
neither with a particular model of planning, nor even
a mere substitution of the free market for planning,
but with establishing a direct access of imperialist
agencies to the Indian countryside through a bunch
of NGOs who are in no way accountable to the people.
What is often missed by those who do not see the difference
between Kerala-style decentralization and the World
Bank concept is that the LSGIs are also a part of
the State apparatus. Transferring certain responsibilities
to the LSGIs therefore is tantamount to a redistribution
of responsibility within the State structure, but
a redistribution that has the aim of enforcing greater
accountability of the State. The concept of "users'
sovereignty" invoked above was linked essentially
to this greater accountability. Such "sovereignty"
could be exercised only because of the introduction
of greater accountability on the State for which decentralization
was a means. To be sure, the sheer fact of decentralization
would not bring about all these changes; on the contrary,
in regions where the poor are unorganized, decentralization
could have the opposite effect of strengthening the
local oppressors, who, prior to decentralization,
might have been kept in check through the actions
of "benevolent" elements of the bureaucracy.
But, in principle, democratic decentralization is
to be preferred, no matter how unsatisfactory its
immediate results (this point of course is not relevant
for Kerala) , because it enforces greater accountability
on the State and restores greater subjectivity to
the people.
Imperialist decentralization however has nothing to
do with the subjectivity of the people, even when
the people are consulted on their preferences, since
it operates not through statutory institutions but
through voluntary organizations. Indeed, its very
objective is to reduce the scope for the operations
of statutory institutions, and their replacement by
voluntary agencies which are either directly funded
by imperialist donors, or are funded from the State
budget which in turn has come to depend heavily on
imperialist sources for funding social sector expenditures.
In short, World Bank decentralization refers essentially
to a withdrawal of the State from the social sector,
while the aim of decentralized planning was not a
withdrawal but greater accountability of an activist
State.
Enfeebling the third world State, even the third world
bourgeois State, breaking down whatever relative autonomy
it may have vis-à-vis imperialism, and reducing
it to the status of either a collaborationist or a
client or even a puppet State, is a persistent objective
of imperialism. This is because a relatively autonomous
third world State can act as a bulwark against imperialist
domination. This enfeeblement is brought about through
a number of different instruments. For instance, the
imposition of neo-liberal economic policies necessarily
results in an accentuation of the fiscal crisis of
the third world State, which is then used to induct
direct funding of social sector expenditures by imperialist
agencies (the DPEP is a classic example of this and
there are designated "World Bank districts"
in India where this important social sector expenditure
has become the responsibility of the Bank). The Bank's
notion of "decentralization" is a part of
this project of enfeebling the third world State,
and is therefore well-integrated into the plethora
of neo-liberal policies. One aspect of these policies
which has been well recognized is the withdrawal of
the State from an autonomous active role in the social
sector in favour of the market; the other aspect which
has received less attention however is the withdrawal
of the State from an activist role in this sector
in favour of imperialist agencies which then penetrate
the countryside both directly and through imperialist-funded
NGOs.
It follows from what has just been said that, Kerala-style
decentralization, far from being indistinguishable
from imperialist decentralization, actually faces
a threat from the latter, or at any rate from the
package of policies of which the latter is an integral
part. The real problem with Kerala-style decentralization
in the present context lies in other words in the
fact that it tends to get undermined not because of
its own failings but from outside: from the pursuit
of the neo-liberal agenda by the country's government,
and from its efforts to push neo-liberal "reforms"
on the State governments.
The neo-liberal dispensation necessarily implies an
accentuation of the fiscal travails of the Central
government, which the latter in turn passes down to
the State governments. It is noteworthy that during
the nineties the ratio of the Central government's
tax revenue to the GDP went down while that of the
State governments went up, and yet the latter were
afflicted with acute fiscal crises by the beginning
of the new century. It is not just one or two States
that are facing fiscal difficulties but virtually
every State, though to differing degrees. Reduced
transfers from the Centre, and the pay-hikes in the
wake of the Central government's acceptance of the
Fifth Pay Commission report, have of course played
their part in precipitating this fiscal crisis of
the State governments. But a very important contributing
factor has been the sharp increase in interest rates
on State government debt.
The Central government's own borrowing rates have
gone up with the end of the ad hoc Treasury Bills
route, which came with neo-liberalism. What is more,
the Centre has deliberately, gratuitously, and quite
unwarrantedly, jacked up the rates of interest it
charges on loans to the State governments, and used
the debt-trap to which it has pushed the State governments
to impose neo-liberal policies on them. It has even
used the offices of the Eleventh Finance Commission
to impose "reforms" on States as a pre-condition
for their obtaining funds that are due to them anyway
under the Constitution[5]!
With the State governments starved of funds, the LSGIs
too find themselves short of resources. No worthwhile
"local level planning" is possible under
these circumstances. Besides, when the State governments
are short of funds, they turn to international agencies
like the ADB or the World Bank for financing investment
projects in rural areas which they themselves would
have otherwise done[6]
. These agencies in turn have their own ways of allocating
their funds between projects, and monitoring the use
of their funds in rural infrastructure, which either
preclude the involvement of the LSGIs or give them
at best a token role[7]
. A vibrant programme of decentralization, which can
lead to the greater assertiveness of the rural poor,
thus runs counter in a fundamental sense to the trajectory
of development of a neo-liberal economic regime.
References
Dobb,
M.H. (1969) Wefare Economics and the Economics of
Socialism, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
The
World Bank (1997) “The State in a Changing World”,
World Development Report 1997,
Oxford University Press, Oxford.
The World Bank (2000) “Entering the Twenty-first Century”,
World Development Report 1999-2000, Oxford University
Press, Oxford.
The
World Bank (2002) “Building Institutions for Markets”,
World Development Report 2002, Oxford University Press,
Oxford.
[4] See for instance The World Bank
(1997, 2000, 2002).
[5] A dissenting note by Dr.Amaresh
Bagchi, a member of the Eleventh Finance Commission,
took strong exception to this procedure adopted by
the Commission.
[6]This itself is the result of fallacious
reasoning on the part of the Central government. Since
no foreign exchange is required for such investments,
borrowing from domestic banks which are flush with
funds and would put very little "conditionalities"
would have no worse consequences than borrowing from
these agencies which do insist on "conditionalities".
But the Central government is quite liberal in allowing
the States to borrow from these agencies, and charges
much higher interest rates to the states than these
agencies do, while it is very strict in allowing States
to borrow from domestic banks.
[7] When local agencies are to be
involved in the implementation of such projects, then,
as mentioned earlier, NGOs, or parallel institutions
to the LSGIs as in Andhra Pradesh, seem to be the
preferred option.
|