|
|
|
|
Food
Prices and Distribution Margins in India |
|
Feb
3rd 2011, Jayati Ghosh |
|
The
dramatic increase in food inflation over the past two
years has been associated with several surprises. One
major surprise has been how the top economic policy
makers in the country have responded to it. The initial
response was one of apparent disbelief, followed very
quickly by the frequently repeated but thus far unsubstantiated
conviction that prices would come down very soon.
Then
this massive increase in the price of essential commodities
was welcomed, even by those who should know better,
as being a sign of greater material prosperity in the
country and the success of ''pro-poor'' schemes of the
government, reflected in increased demand for food.
Could it be that the economists who are running the
country apparently believed that food demand should
not increase much even in periods of significant aggregate
income growth, and among a population that has the some
of the worst nutrition indicators in the world? Is that
why they did not see any need to work towards increased
supply of food and have been so surprised by even a
slight increase in demand?
As it happens, in fact demand for food has been growing
much more slowly than could be anticipated by both income
and population growth. Much of that has to do with the
distribution of that growth, which has disproportionately
denied benefits to the poor who would naturally consume
more food. But even so, the fact that it is really the
conditions of supply – reflecting the continuing policy
neglect of agriculture as well as the nature of distribution
and the pressures on the market from speculative activity
– that have driven food prices up.
This recognition may be why the official arguments have
changed somewhat recently. Most recently the officially
stated position has been to blame inadequate existing
distribution chains – focusing on their inefficiency,
rather than any speculative pressures that could also
affect supply. This has become the most popular interpretation
of the ongoing food crisis in the corridors of power
and their stenographers in the financial press. This
has consequently led to the demand that modern corporate
retail chains (ideally with FDI) be brought in to manage
food distribution.
As a result, there are now those who have argued that
the only solution to the problem of high food prices
is to bring in FDI in retail! It is argued that this
will reduce wastage in storage and costs of transport
of food items, cut out intermediaries in distribution
and provide food more effectively to consumers at lower
prices.
Of course this argument is rather foolish, at several
levels. First of all, if the traditional supply chains
in food items are so faulty and deficient, why did they
not create such massive food price spikes earlier? Why
was food inflation relatively low in the period until
2006, despite equally rapid GDP growth and the same
system of distribution that is being faulted?
Secondly, if the problem is inadequate infrastructure,
including cold storage facilities and quicker distribution
networks from farm to market, what stopped the government
from more proactive intervention to ensure better cold
storage and other facilities through various incentives
and promotion of more farmers' co-operatives? To announce
such measures only now, as a weak response to a period
of raging food inflation is futile, because obviously
such measures operate only with a significant time lag.
This is all the more so because such proposals are explicitly
mentioned in the Farmers' Commission Report, which has
been lying with the government for half a decade now.
The idea that cold storage and other facilities can
only be developed by large corporates once they get
directly involved in retail food distribution is ridiculous
at best.
Thirdly, this entire argument completely ignores the
critical role that can be played by a public distribution
system in moderating such food price spikes and dampening
inflationary expectations and tendencies of hoarding.
Instead of accepting the failure of the government to
use this system effectively so far, the tendency is
to throw up hands and declare that only the large private
sector can save us, even though international evidence
indicates that corporate monopoly in food trade typically
increases distribution margins rather than reducing
them.
Unfortunately, though, we are forced to take such arguments
seriously because they are being repeated ad nauseum
by the media and pushed into government policies by
corporate lobbies. So let us consider what the recent
evidence on distribution margins indicates.
In fact, there is significant reason to believe that
the margins between wholesale and retail prices of many
important food items have increased in the recent period.
(See MacroScan, Businessline, 23 February 2010) The
point is that this has been happening in a period of
increased corporate involvement in food distribution
and food retail. The share of corporate retail in food
distribution in the country as a whole is estimated
to have tripled in the past four years, and has grown
even faster in major metros and other large cities.
And this is also the period when retail food prices
have shown the greatest increase!
The other point that emerges from a comparison of retails
margins across major towns and cities is that such margins
are lowest in the states (like Tamil Nadu and Kerala)
where there is an extensive, well-developed and reasonably
efficient system of public distribution that provides
a range of food items on a near universal basis to the
population. In regions where such a public distribution
system is weak or non-existent (such as Utter Pradesh
and Bihar) the margins tend to be much higher and growing
faster, even though corporate food retailing in such
regions has been expanding.
So to look at corporate retail as the solution to the
current food price increase is more than irresponsible.
There is no question that the current system of food
procurement from farmers is inadequate, faulty and often
quite anti-farmer. There is much that needs to be reformed
in the way that market yards are organised and in the
options available to farmers to get their produce to
market. There is a range of necessary and possible interventions
for this, most of which have been stated many times
to the government by various Commissions of its own.
Yet thus far the UPA government has done little about
any of these, even in terms of working with state governments
to improve the situation, and instead seems to think
that simply allowing more corporate (and FDI) activity
in retail will allow it to wash its own hands of the
matter.
In this context, consider how retail margins have been
behaving in the very recent past, in just one location,
the city of Delhi. Charts 1, 2 and 3 describe the price
behaviour of three significant but relatively less perishable
food items: rice, sugar and tur dal.
Chart
1 >> Click
to Enlarge
Chart
2 >> Click
to Enlarge
Chart
3 >> Click
to Enlarge
It
is evident that the retail prices have generally been
tracking the wholesale prices in terms of direction
of movement, but still there are some noteworthy variations.
On average, retail margins have increased for all these
commodities, and quite sharply for tur dal. This may
be the result of a number of features, and obviously
requires more investigation. But even so it is worth
noting that Delhi is a city that has witnssed a signfiicant
increase in corporate food retail. And the role of inflationary
expectations in being able to influence retail price
behaviour is obviously much greater for larger players.
The
food prices that have been most talked about of course
are those of onions. Onion prices are widely perceived
to have great political significance, especially in
North India. Because onions like other vegetables are
highly perishable, supply conditions should play a major
role in their price. Charts 4 and 5 describe the wholesale
and retail prices, and the total market arrivals of
onions and tomatoes in the city of Delhi.
The evidence is somewhat surprising. For much of the
period of falling market arrivals over the past year,
onion prices were rather stable and the retail margin
actually shrank. Prices started rising sharply only
in October – and this is the period after which supply
was actually increasing quite sharply! In November and
December, market arrivals increased but prices continued
to shoot up. Surely inflationary expectations and hoarding
must have played roles, along with speculative pressure,
and this was not sufficiently counteracted by public
intervention through its own food distribution network.
Chart
4 >> Click
to Enlarge
Chart
5 >> Click
to Enlarge
The case of tomato prices is similarly interesting.
It is evident that neither wholesale nor retail prices
had much relation to market arrivals, even for this
extremely perishable commodity. But what the period
of higher prices has been associated with is a significant
increase in retail margins in October and November.
Dealing
systematically with the problem of high food prices
in a context of a largely hungry population should normally
be a priority issue for any government. There are certainly
crucial medium term policies that reverse the longer
run neglect of agriculture, that must be implemented.
The issue of rapidly rising cultivation costs that are
making farming unviable once again, needs to be addressed
in a holistic way. The concerns of storage, distribution
and post-harvest technology also need to dealt with.
But in the short run, the problem cannot be avoided
by talking of astrologers and the inability of mere
humans to predict the future. Instead, creating a viable
and effective public distribution system that will counteract
tendencies to price spikes in essential commodities
is an immediate requirement.
|
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|