|
|
|
|
Fallacies
and Silences in the Approach to the Eleventh Plan |
|
Jul
26th 2006, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
It
has already been pointed out in a previous column that
in its Approach to the Eleventh Five-Year Plan, the
Planning Commission has adopted an uncritical ''trickle-down''
approach to economic growth, by making the basic objective
the achievement of a certain target annual GDP growth
figure - either 7.8 or 9 per cent per annum - and effectively
assuming that all social goals will be achieved by this.
This is almost criminal, since the same Approach Paper
has tucked away in it the first official acknowledgement
that until now the country has been told a fairy tale
about poverty reduction during the 1990s. Until recently,
the growth-first argument has made much of the contested
official claim that poverty declined from 36 per cent
in 1993-94 to 26 per cent in 1999-2000 or by 10 per
cent over a 6 year period. It is now revealed that the
comparable figure for 2004-05 is 28 per cent, which
implies only 8 per cent reduction over a 11 year period.
This implies that despite all the hype on growth, it
is now official that the rate of poverty reduction after
1990 has been at only half the rate between 1977 to
1990.
So in fact it matters great deal whether the pattern
of growth that in planned for is actually ''inclusive''
or not, and the Planning Commission should really have
focused all its attention on ensuring that this most
crucial of goals is achieved. However, the combination
of silences and misplaced emphases on particular areas
creates an overall approach which falls very far short
of even envisaging truly inclusive growth. In particular,
the Approach Paper fails to address or wrongly deals
with five critical areas that are not only essential
for inclusive growth but also the most burning policy
issues of the present time. These areas are control
over and loss of land; employment generation; agriculture
and food security; health; and education.
The land question
For a while now, issues relating to land control and
assets distribution had gone out of fashion in policy
discussion. However, they were always critical in affecting
ground realities, and now the issues involved are so
pressing that they simply cannot be wished away and
must be addressed directly by the state at different
levels. It is not simply that the pattern of landownership
and control has been concentrated and subject to a significant
degree of gender discrimination. It is also that recent
patterns of development have created much more dispossession
and dislocation, especially among the peasantry and
forest dwellers, and this has created not only much
more material distress but also widespread social tension.
The NSS data on landholdings, as expressed in the data
collected in the 59th Round of the survey and shown
in Chart 1, indicate a significant increase in landlessness
among rural households. According to these data, the
proportion of landless rural households had been broadly
stable for three decades from the early 1970s at around
28 per cent, and had come down to 22 per cent in 1991-92.
But the data relating to 2002-03 indicate a very sharp
increase to nearly one-third of rural households. A
similar (and even more accentuated) increase had been
evident from the NSS employment survey, which suggested
that well above one-third of rural households had no
land in 1999-2000.
This growing landlessness is not fortuitous: it is the
result of a process that has been marked in the countryside
over the last decade, of reduced economic viability
of cultivation, that has particularly squeezed small
producers. This is discussed in more detail below, but
the moot point in this context is that financial stress,
including the inability to repay loans taken for cultivation
and for other purposes, has forced many farmers to sell
their lands and join the landless population. This process
is likely to have been especially strong among farmers
with marginal holdings, which may explain why their
proportion has fallen slightly in the most recent period.
Chart
1 >>
This
problem assumes particular significance because - as
will be evident below - this loss of an important asset
has not been accompanied by expansion in other economic
opportunities, so that the growing number of landless
rural households have not just lost real wealth, they
are deprived of a basic source of livelihood. This is
a basic problem which the Planning Commission must address
if its desire for ''more inclusive growth'' is not to
be entirely imaginary.
In
addition, the economic growth process has involved increasing
displacement of people from their land, with inadequate
or no compensation and rehabilitation measures. Such
displacement has resulted not only from large irrigation
projects but also for urban expansion, increases in
transport networks such as roads and railways, and the
like. Tribal populations have been disproportionately
affected by this. The inadequacy of current rehabilitation
practices, and the possibilities for social discord,
have been recognised in the Approach Paper. But more
needs to be done than simply ''frame a transparent set
of policy rules'', and the Planning Commission should
really have used this opportunity to reconsider the
strategy of growth so as to ensure that displacement
and dispossession are themselves minimised as far as
possible. Instead, the Approach actually calls for dilution
or removal of urban land ceiling acts by the state governments,
thus reinforcing land monopolies of a few large players.
Despite these pressing and increasingly urgent concerns,
discussion of land reforms - which are once again a
topical issue - finds no place in the document. Nor
is there any concern about the problem of recognising
the land rights of women, and ensuring that women be
given pattas in the event of any redistribution or rehabilitation.
Employment generation
Despite all evidence to the contrary - most obviously
from the direct experience of the past and current Plan
periods - the Planning Commission adopts a trickle-down
approach whereby it is assumed that output growth will
automatically generate more employment, and that too
in sufficient quantities to meet the growing labour
force. Yet it is obvious to all that the major failure
of the growth process, and the most important impediment
to ''inclusive'' growth, is the lack of adequate employment
generation.
Recent NSS data, described in Chart 2, show a very sharp
increase in open unemployment rates for men and women
in both rural and urban areas, despite this being the
period of highest recorded rates of aggregate output
growth. In a country where there is no unemployment
benefit and no social protection for those without jobs,
and where most of the poor have no option but to find
some work simply to survive, such an increase in open
unemployment is remarkable and historically unprecedented.
It points to a huge absence of productive income opportunities
across both urban and rural areas. And it shows very
clearly that ''trickle down'' cannot be relied upon to
generate jobs.
Yet the discussion on employment generation is probably
the weakest section of the Approach Paper, whereas it
should have received the central focus. It is not listed
at the start as among the most important challenges,
and casual attitude permeates the rest of the document.
There is no serious consideration of how to ensure that
the growth process will actually create more jobs. Even
worse, policies that will actually operate to reduce
employment are strewn throughout the paper.
Chart
2 >>
For
example, the section on promoting industrial growth
argues that ''externally the gradual reduction of tariffs
on non-agricultural products should continue'' without
providing any justification for this, even though it
is now evident that excess manufacturing capacity creation
in many countries is pushing down prices of manufactured
goods and the threat of such imports is harming small
scale producers, who are the largest employers. It also
argues for acceleration of the process of de-reserving
many industrial sectors which were earlier reserved
for small-scale industries, which again is bound to
adversely affect industrial employment. In another section,
the Approach argues for opening up retail trade to foreign
players in order to ''benefit consumers'' - even though
it is well known that the rationalisation and concentration
that typically result in such entry are likely to throw
millions of petty retailers out of business and thus
dramatically reduce employment in this sector.
There
is apparently a belief that labour market flexibility,
which is a euphemism for reduced protection to workers
in the organised sector, will automatically ensure more
employment creation, even though more than 90 per cent
of Indian workers currently have no protection at all,
and there is little international or domestic experience
to justify this hackneyed argument. Even while the Planning
Commission effectively wants to remove protection from
workers in the unorganised sector, there appears to
be a general lack of concern with the fate of unprotected
workers generally. Thus, it is surprising that the Approach
makes no mention at all of an extremely important new
initiative of providing social security to informal
sector workers, that has been proposed by the National
Commission on the Unorganised Sector in its recently
released report.
The agrarian crisis and food security
The persistent crisis in agriculture is well known;
indeed, the UPA government recognised it and insisted
that greater policy focus on agriculture would form
one of the basic elements of its economic strategy.
More recently, the continuing and even increasing incidence
of farmers’ suicides in some particularly affected regions
has prompted the announcements of specific relief ''packages''
which may have more cosmetic than real effects.
Nevertheless, the causes of the current agrarian distress
are now widely recognised. The combination of continuously
higher input prices and volatile output prices, along
with reduced access to institutional credit and inadequate
public attention to the problems of dryland farming,
have created problems for all farmers, but obviously
the smaller and financially weaker sections of the peasantry
have been the worst affected. Even the measure that
are necessary to deal with this are now known to state
and central governments. In fact, the National Commission
on Farmers headed by M. S. Swaminathan has made a series
of important recommendations, both general and specific
and long term as well as short term, to address this
current crisis.
In this context, the very least that could be expected
of the Planning Commission was that this context and
the specific measures already available for discussion
would be taken on board in the Approach Paper. Unfortunately,
this does not seem to be the case. In fact, the discussion
suggests that the important reports of the Farmers’
Commission have not even been read carefully! The problems
of agriculture are dealt with simplistically, based
on the assumption that encouraging corporate farming
and diversification into horticulture will be enough
to make agriculture viable and buoyant again. The basic
problems facing most farmers in the country, especially
small peasants, are not addressed at all: rising prices
of inputs and very volatile output prices; problems
of access to assured water supply and difficulties of
raising cash crops on dryland areas; the inadequate
support to related activities such as livestock rearing;
poor extension services which do not provide the latest
or relevant information to farmers; the exclusion of
the vast majority of petty cultivators such as tenant
and women farmers, from the ambit of institutional credit;
the inadequate protection provided by crop insurance
schemes, and so on.
In addition to this, the real and growing problem of
food insecurity has not received any attention at all.
The dominant public perception is of major and disturbing
changes in the food economy of India, given the recent
need to import food grains, pulses and sugar for the
first time in thirty years, as part of the measures
to stem the steep rise in prices of essential commodities,
as well as the evidence of growing hunger and even starvation
reports from certain areas. The public distribution
system has been run down and does not provide adequate
access to the poor: it urgently needs expansion to be
made universal. The expansion of the ICDS scheme and
its nutrition component similarly is something that
has even been mandated by the Supreme Court, although
thus far the central government has not fulfilled its
legal obligations in this matter. So the current context
is one in which food security - both on the ground and
at the macro level - should surely have been a priority
among our planners. Surely, the Planning Commission’
s silence on this matter is deafening.
Health and education
These were declared to be the central concerns of the
UPA government, and are associated with flagship programmes
such as the National Rural Health Mission and progressive
legislation such as the Right to Education Bill. yet
even in these crucial social sectors, the mindset displayed
in the Approach Paper is still very much that which
was displayed by the earlier government, of raising
user fees and reducing so-called ''subsidies'' in areas
which must by publicly funded.
With respect to health provision, the Approach Paper
talks of raising user charges, which is bound to exclude
most of the poor in what is already a hugely underfunded
public provision. In addition, there is an extraordinary
suggestion to provide remuneration to public health
workers by the service! Surely it is obvious that providing
decent public services requires adequate numbers of
decently paid personnel, without which the services
are likely to be substandard. In a matter as crucial
as health, linking pay to ''productivity'' or ''delivery''
however defined will not only militate against such
workers, it will also create incentives of the most
undesirable kind with unwanted social consequences.
Similarly, there is an argument for higher fees in higher
education, despite the well known problems of social
exclusion that can result from this and the presence
of significant externalities that make higher education
also clearly a merit good. Another problematic proposal
relates developing a voucher system, which has been
proposed not only for secondary and higher education
but even for primary education. According to such a
scheme, children would be provided with vouchers with
which they could pay fees in private schools as well
as public schools, thereby ''enlarging choice''. This
idea, which comes from a failed US experience, completely
ignores the stark realities of the government school
system at present, which is desperately underfunded.
Official estimates suggest that around one-fifth of
schools do not have a building at all, and another one-fourth
have only one room. More than 15 per cent of elementary
schools function with only one teacher and another 20
per cent one fifth with only two teachers for five classes.
In this appalling context, surely the priority in expenditure
must be to provide more infrastructure, teachers etc.
in public schooling, without which no quality improvements
there are possible, and not to indirectly subsidise
private schools.
There are numerous other problems with different suggestions
made in the Approach. In general they stem from an underlying
perception that creating a profitable environment for
private sector functioning will be enough to fulfil
most social goals, and no particular planning strategy
is required for this. Coming from the organisation charged
with handling public expenditure for development, this
is a disturbing perspective.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|