The rise of finance capital affects the ability of governments to undertake deficit spending even directly. Finance capital is wary of the possible inflationary consequences of deficit-financed expenditure, since such inflation affects the real value of financial assets and the real rate of return on such assets. It is also wary of the possibility that governments resorting to deficit-financed expenditure may manage interest rates in a manner aimed at keeping down the cost of their borrowing requirements. Not surprisingly, financial agents constantly run down deficit-based spending and often respond by pulling out of economies characterized by high deficits on the governments' budgets. Fear of the destabilizing effects this would have puts direct pressure on governments to abjure deficit-financed spending.
 
The reality is that inasmuch as this fear of deficit spending afflicts each and every government, we should expect the adoption of a more deflationary stance across countries that could result in an overall slowing of global growth. The shift to a more deflationary stance did, in fact, occur. As Chart 3 shows, government fiscal balances in the 1990s reflect a sharp reduction in the level of deficit spending in the principal developed countries, with the exception of Japan, where the level of deficit spending increased sharply. In fact, by 1998, the fiscal balance in the US and the UK had turned positive.
Chart 3 >>
 
It cannot be denied that this shift to a deflationary stance in fiscal policy across the major developed countries would have had an adverse impact on growth. To start with, in all these countries the stimulus to growth afforded by government expenditure would have been considerably dampened, since deficit spending relative to GDP fell in a period when tax rates were being substantially reduced to spur private initiative.  This would have been aggravated by the global effects of reduced deficit spending in the world's leading economy, the US, whose currency serves as the world's reserve currency and is therefore considered 'as good as gold'. In the decades immediately after World War II, America used its hegemonic position and the fact  that it was home to the world's reserve currency, to function as though it faced no national budget constraint. It could finance expenditures worldwide, including those on policing the world, independent of whether it had a surplus on its current account or not. It did not have to earn foreign exchange to sustain such expenditures, since the dollar was accepted in any quantity worldwide.
 
The willingness of the US to undertake such deficit-financed expenditures based on its strength as the world's leading power obviously meant that the United States served as an engine for global growth. The post-War boom in the world economy is attributable in no small measure to this tendency. Conversely, the decision of the US government to move out of a regime in which it sustained a high and persistent deficit on its budget to one in which its budget showed a surplus must have substantially worsened the deflationary tendency in the world system. The consequent tendency towards deflation is reflected in price trends worldwide (Chart 6), which point to a significant and continuous decline in inflation rates across the major industrialized nations throughout the 1990s.
Chart 6 >>
 
These circumstances render the picture of de-synchronized economic performance during the 1990s even more puzzling. To start with, we have the counter-intuitive trend wherein the US, which saw a dramatic transition from deficit to surplus budgets, turned out to be a remarkable performer growth-wise precisely in those years in which that transition was occurring. Next, barring Japan, growth in many of the developed countries, especially the UK, was not very much worse in the 1990s than it was in the previous decades, despite the dampening effects of their own deflationary fiscal stance and that of the US. Finally, we have the unusual fact that despite the consistent effort of the Japanese government to pump-prime its economy through a series of reflationary packages, the Japanese economy performed poorly right through the 1990s, except for a brief episode of growth around 1996.
 
The first step in unravelling this puzzling set of circumstances is to recognize that in the era of finance, the stimulus to growth has to come from the private sector. Since private investors need some inducement to invest, private sector-led growth in any economy must be stimulated by a rise in consumption expenditure either in the domestic economy or abroad, which translates into increased demand for domestic firms. There is reason to believe that the rise to dominance of finance does contribute to such an increase in private expenditure. Financial flows and financial liberalization can make a self-correcting contribution to neutralizing the deflationary bias resulting from reduced government expenditure in two possible ways: (a) they can permit a burgeoning of debt-financed consumption and housing expenditures that help sustain private and public spending so long as borrowers and lenders coexist; (b) they can trigger financial developments that increase the financial wealth of households, which in turn, through the 'wealth effect' encourages consumption and even dis-saving.

 
 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2002