The situation appears
to be deteriorating rapidly. According to the Solvent Extractors'
Association of India, the import of vegetable oils during the oil year
1998-99 stood at 4.39 million tonnes, which was more than double the
figure of 2.08 million tonnes in the previous year. Quoting Oil World
weekly, they argue that imports during 1999-2000 could be as high as 4.7
to 4.9 million tonnes. Refined palmolein reportedly accounts for around 60
per cent of these exports.
Overall India's weakening competitive edge in recent times is essentially
the result of a sharp decline in international prices. The international
prices of agricultural commodities, which registered a sharp rise during
1992-96, have recorded an even sharper fall since then, taking them to a
decadal low. According to the food and agricultural raw materials price
indices of the International Monetary Fund, prices fell by 13 and 16 per
cent in 1998, after similar declines in the previous year. Prices are
projected to fall further in 1999.
It is not just the fall in prices that is a matter of concern, but the
inter-commodity variations in impact of imports on domestic prices. With
pulses and edible oil imports being placed under OGL as part of
liberalisation, the real prices of these commodities have either declined
or remained stagnant. On the other hand, there are crops which have seen
increase in prices in real terms during these years. This obviously
results in a shift of acreage away from certain crops to others, making
India
increasingly import dependent in some areas. At one level, this is a
matter of concern from the point of view of food security, since it is
likely that prices would remain high for various commercial crops that
have a large international demand while remaining low for a range of food
crops. But that is not all. Trade liberalisation could lead to substantial
instability. Since India's large demand for particular commodities is
likely to affect international prices substantially, a shift out of one
crop in domestic production and in its favour in imports could trigger
prices increases that induce acreage shift reversals. Such price and
output instability is hardly the recipe for building competitive
capabilities, which is the ostensible aim of liberalisation.
These possibilities that trade liberalisation could
adversely affect agriculture need to be viewed in the light of evidence
which suggests that the overall benefits to agriculture from
liberalisation have thus far been limited. One fall out of overall trade
liberalisation was to be a shift in the terms of trade between agriculture
and manufacturing in favour of agriculture, as a result of a fall in
manufactured goods prices and a rise in agricultural prices. However, as
Chart 12 shows, while the terms of trade have been in favour of
agriculture during the 1990s, the gains in those terms were registered
during the 1980s and not the 1990s. During the 1990s, the terms have trade
have fluctuated around a more or less stagnant trend, and have equalled
the 1991-92 level only in one other year. And if our analysis of the
likely price consequences of liberalisation materialise, there is a
possibility of a decline in those terms in the years to come.
Chart 12 >>
In sum, liberalisation of trade, even to the extent that it
had proceeded before the Exim policy announced in April this year, has not
delivered the promise of benefits to agriculture that it held out. On the
other hand, there are signs that the consequences for agriculture could
prove adverse in future. The case for caution while advocating further
liberalisation of agricultural trade either at home or at the WTO is
therefore obvious. |