This fact of indifferent
industrial performance did influence the conduct of the now autonomous
central bank. In the initial years of liberalisation, the battle against
inflation was the RBI's principal concern. But this battle was soon
won without much effort. After the initial period of monetary stringency
that accompanied IMF-style adjustment, the RBI itself was hard put to
curb money supply growth which its monetarist faith suggested was the
key to reducing inflation. In fact, as Chart 5 shows, broad money grew
by over 19 per cent a year during the first half of the 1990s. This
was partly because, even while a fall in credit to the government limited
the rise in the central bank's assets, the inflow of dollars into India's
liberalised financial markets was forcing the RBI to demand and buy
dollars in order to prevent an appreciation of the increasingly market-determined
value of the rupee. As Chart 8 shows capital inflows rose sharply to
more than $.8.5 billion in 1993-94 and 1994-95. This rise was clearly
on account of large inflows of portfolio investments (Table 1), in response
to which the RBI had to purchase dollars to prevent an appreciation
of the rupee. In the event, the foreign currency assets of the central
bank tended to rise, increasing the high-powered money base and therefore
the level of money supply. But this did not defeat the RBI's drive to
keep inflation under control, since the liberalisation of imports in
the context of a decline in inflation worldwide and the reduction in
the expansionary stimulus provided by government spending was in itself
contributing to a dampening of inflation.
Table 1 >>
With inflation
proving to be less of a problem, the RBI shifted the focus of its policy
to growth. Since financial reform required a further curtailment of
an expansionary stimulus provided by government spending, the only instrument
that seemed to be available to spur industrial growth was a reduction
in interest rates. However, nominal interest rates in the system had
reached extremely high levels in the wake of reform. And this high rate
of interest persisted even as access to liquidity in the system was
eased as a result of the rising foreign currency reserves. There was
one obvious reason why interest rates were sticky downwards. This was
the high floor that risk free government bonds provided to the structure
of interest rates. With the government deprived of access to cheap funds
from the mint as a result of the curb on the issue of ad hoc
Treasury Bills, it had to finance its persisting fiscal deficits by
borrowing from the open market at market-determined rates. Once the
banks had met their statutorily required investment levels in government
securities, government bonds could be placed in the market only if the
interest rates on such investment offered a good enough spread to the
banks relative to the deposit rates paid by them. Given the relative
high interest rates that depositors could obtain from other investments
in other savings instruments like National Savings Certificates and
Provident Funds and in more risky holdings of equity, deposit rates
had to be kept relatively high to attract funds into the banking system.
This meant that the interest rates offered on government bonds had to
remain high as well. Since these were virtually risk-free investments,
carrying as they do a sovereign guarantee, these relatively high interest
rates on government bonds defined the floor to the structure of interest
rates which at one time stretched to maximum levels of well above 20
per cent.
Faced with this
situation and given its resolve to bring down interest rates, the RBI
moved in four directions. First, it relaxed controls on interest rates
on deposits, giving banks the flexibility to reduce them on longer term
deposits and raise them on short-term deposits, so as to reduce their
average interest costs without curbing deposit growth. Second, it substantially
enhanced liquidity in the system by systematically bringing down the
cash reserve ratio and releasing funds to be provided as credit by the
banks. Third, it reduced by as much as 4 percentage points the Bank
Rate, which is the rate at which banks can obtain finance from the central
bank and therefore serves as an indicative rate for the market for funds.
And finally, it colluded with the government in its effort to bring
down the rate of interest on small savings instruments and provident
funds, so as to encourage households investments in market instruments
as well as to reduce the interest burden of the government which is
the principal borrower of funds invested through those channels.
This combination
of initiatives has indeed been successful in bringing down interest
rates, making the now autonomous central bank appear doubly successful.
It could claim success in dampening inflation and it could be satisfied
with the results of its joint effort with the government to bring down
interest rates. However, the objective behind the drive to reduce interest
rates, namely, that of stimulating industrial growth remains unrealised.
After a temporary reprieve during 1999-2000, the industrial sector is
back to the sluggish performance recorded since 1997-98. And even during
1999-2000, the recovery in growth does not seem to have stimulated investment.
It is this factor which possibly explains the slower growth of commercial
credit and money supply during that year. The reason industrial sluggishness
is, of course, the lack of any expansionary stimulus. While government
expenditure net of interest payments is down relative to GDP, exports
which were to provide the new engine of growth in the wake of reform
have remained at disappointing levels. |