The point to note
is that the lack of any fiscal stimulus is in large part the result
of the effort to give the central bank greater independence. This, as
discussed earlier, has required not just a curb on the fiscal deficit,
but also the abolishment of the practice of financing it with low interest
ad hoc Treasury Bills. Thus the curb on the deficit, during a
period of shrinking revenues, has been accompanied by a rise in the
interest burden on the government's budget. Not surprisingly, the role
of government expenditure as a stimulus to industrial growth has been
substantially eroded. What is appalling is that this has occurred at
a time when the combination of burgeoning foodstocks that are proving
to be an embarrassment, large foreign exchange reserves, low inflation
and high unutilised capacity in industry, makes an obvious case for
a major fiscal stimulus aimed at raising output and employment without
stoking inflation. But that opportunity has been lost by the adherence
to an orthodox monetary and fiscal policy regime that emphasises central
bank autonomy.
What is more,
even autonomy has proved to be limited, because of the role of volatile
capital flows into the economy. As mentioned earlier, one area in which
the RBI has been forced to be active in the wake of reform is the liberalised
foreign exchange market. The supply and demand for dollars in that market
does influence the level of the exchange rate. However, in the wake
of financial reform the supply of dollars is no more determined by the
inflow of foreign exchange due to current account transactions such
as exports and remittances. Rather, inflows on the capital account in
the form of private debt and foreign direct and portfolio investment,
are a major determinant of supply at the margin.
Such inflows have
increased significantly in the wake of the financial reform of the 1990s.
But such increased inflows have not been matched by the demand for dollars
from a not-too-buoyant economy. In the event, an excess supply of foreign
exchange in the market has tended to push up the value of the rupee
at a time when India has consistently recorded a deficit on its current
account. To combat this, the central bank has had to regularly demand
and purchase dollars, resulting in a substantial rise in the foreign
currency assets of the central bank. Such a rise as we have mentioned
earlier, by contributing to money supply increases, limits the autonomy
of the central bank on the monetary policy front.
But that is not
all. The volatility in foreign capital flows tends to further limit
the manoeuvrability of the central bank even further. Consider for example
the year 1999-2000, which was one in which foreign capital inflows into
the country, having fallen from $12 billion in 1996-97 to $9.8 bilion
in 1997-98 to $8.6 billion in 1998-999, rose once again to touch $10.2
billion (Chart 8). This should have strengthened the rupee. It did not
because the RBI, as in the past, stepped in to buy dollars, increase
the demand for that currency and stabilise its value vis-à-vis
the rupee. Net purchases of foreign currency from the market by the
Reserve Bank of India amounted to $3.25 billion between end-March 1999
and end-March 2000. These purchases resulted, among other things, in
an increase in the foreign currency assets of the central bank from
$29.5 billion at the end of 1998-99 to $35.1 billion at the end of 1999-2000.
Most of these purchases occurred between end-September 1999 and end-February
2000 (Chart 7). The large demand for dollars that this intervention
by the RBI in foreign exchange markets resulted in, helped keep the
rupee relatively stable during financial year 1999-2000. However, that
stability concealed a new source of vulnerability. As Chart 9 indicates,
the share of stable capital flows (or flows other than portfolio investments,
short-term debt and NRI deposits), which had risen to account for almost
90 per cent of all flows by 1998/99, fell to 46 per cent of the total
in 1999-2000.
Chart 7 >>
Chart 8
>> Chart
9 >>
This vulnerability partly explains why things have changed suddenly
this financial year. Thus over the first three months of 2000-01, for
which we have information, while exports have staged a recovery, imports
have grown even faster, resulting in an increase in the trade deficit
relative to the corresponding period of the previous year. But what
has been an even more depressing influence on the rupee are signs that
portfolio investments have turned negative, and rapidly so. Net FII
investments, which in April stood at $617 million, fell to $111 million
in May, and turned negative as of June, with outflows estimated at $218
million in June and around $300 million in July.
Clearly, institutional investors are cashing in a part of their past
investments and diverting funds to other markets. According to market
sources, the strengthening of interest rates in the US and the recovery
of markets elsewhere in Asia have encouraged a shift of FII focus away
from India. The point is that this consequence of developments elsewhere
has had a dampening effect on the value of the rupee, which is now perceived
as being "overvalued".
This should not have mattered much, especially given the fact that the
rupee has appreciated vis-a-vis a range of currencies other than the
dollar. However, given the liberalised nature of financial markets,
any perception that a currency is overvalued and that it is headed downwards
sets off speculation in the currency. And once such speculative activity
is triggered, speculative expectations tend to realise themselves leading
to a downward spiral in the currency's value. The RBI's "knee-jerk"
reaction to the recent slide in the rupee's value suggests that it believed
that some authorised dealers and exporters were acquiring and holding
dollars for speculative purposes, so that an ostensibly warranted and
welcome depreciation of the rupee could soon turn into collapse, with
a host of adverse implications. It is only that perception that can
explain the heavy-handed response of the central bank in the form of
a squeeze in liquidity, hike in interest rates and a cap on dollar holdings
in EEFC accounts.
Whatever the sequence of events that led up to that perception, it is
clear that the whimsical behaviour of foreign investors and speculative
activity in India's liberalised foreign exchange markets has forced
the RBI to divert from its well planned monetary policy thrust aimed
at stimulating growth. This substantially erodes the validity of the
view that reform has rendered the central bank more autonomous and monetary
policy more effective. Despite the accumulation of foreign currency
assets in the hands of the RBI, it has found itself in a situation where
it has had to make changes to the Bank Rate, the CRR and the ease of
access to foreign exchange, in order to counter speculation in the market
for foreign exchange. And yet, the evidence of success of the effort
at stabilising the rupee is still ambiguous. |