|
|
|
|
Financial
Convergence in Asia* |
|
Sep
5th 2012, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
The
discussion on the direction that financial regulation
should take in Asia inevitably turns to the diversity
in regulation across countries in its search for an
appropriate combination of policies and measures.
The presumption here is that the rich diversity in
the region offers a menu from which a combination
of institutions and instruments and a corresponding
regulatory framework can be put together. The case
for focusing on Asian policy has been strengthened
by the resilience displayed by Asian countries during
the global financial crisis of 2007-08 and after,
despite their substantial integration with the global
financial system.
While there is a case for such an effort to learn
from diversity, there is also much evidence that monetary,
fiscal and financial policies and the associated macroeconomic
scenario have been converging across Asian countries
since the onset of financial liberalisation and more
so since the Southeast Asian financial crisis of 1997.
The ostensible role of the 1997 crisis in influencing
macroeconomic policy in these countries has been much
discussed after the global crisis. The 1997 experience,
it is argued, persuaded these countries to maintain
a high volume of foreign exchange reserves to deal
with any volatility in cross-border capital flows
and excessive fluctuations in their currencies, leading
to a situation of capital flows from South to North,
rather than North to South as under the Bretton Woods
system.
Among the many commonalities in the evolution of financial
structures in the region, there are a few that are
particularly striking. The first is, of course, the
evidence of the growing integration of these economies
with the international financial system, which is
reflected in a rising ratio of net capital flows to
GDP in almost all of these countries after 2003 and
an increase in foreign bank claims on these countries
in recent years (Table 1). This is because, even while
reserves accumulate, these countries continue with
open door policies that encourage cross-border inflows
of capital. The resulting outcome is relevant not
merely because it amounts to a reversal of the trend
seen in the immediate post-1997 years, when as a result
of the crisis the access of many countries to foreign
finance appeared to be falling. Clearly, countries
now are able to attract capital and are also unable
to avoid or are willing to address the dangers (in
the form of balance of payments and/or currency crises)
of dependence on volatile cross-border flows.
From a policy point of view, the increase in the presence
of foreign capital has necessitated changes in the
regulatory framework governing finance in these countries.
Governments in the region have adopted more liberal
rules with regard to the functioning of different
kinds of markets and institutions, provided greater
space for new instruments such as derivatives, and
shown a willingness to shift to globally accepted
rules for regulation. One consequence has been a rapid
shift to a Basel-type regulatory framework for the
banking system. In fact, countries in the region are
on average more eager to move on to Basel III than
seems to be the case even in the developed countries
where the crisis that forced the transition from Basel
II to III occurred. The message seems to be that if
countries choose to adopt a macroeconomic policy framework
that emphasises the need to attract large volumes
of foreign capital, reform of the regulatory structure
governing finance in a common, globally dictated direction
seems to be a prerequisite.
Table
1: International bank claims, consolidated
(Bn USD) |
|
Europe
|
|
2005-Q4 |
2007-Q1 |
2009-Q1 |
2012-Q1 |
China |
44.3 |
90.0 |
98.7 |
261.0 |
Hong
Kong |
192.6 |
223.8 |
240.5 |
359.9 |
Indonesia |
12.6 |
19.5 |
22.7 |
36.1 |
India |
49.0 |
78.6 |
112.1 |
150.6 |
South
Korea |
120.7 |
165.5 |
159.5 |
161.4 |
Malaysia |
32.0 |
43.7 |
39.9 |
57.0 |
Singapore |
70.6 |
101.0 |
120.3 |
179.8 |
Thailand |
11.5 |
17.5 |
15.5 |
21.8 |
|
Japan
|
|
2005-Q4 |
2007-Q1 |
2009-Q1 |
2012-Q1 |
China |
13.1 |
18.6 |
24.3 |
52.9 |
Hong
Kong |
19.2 |
23.9 |
28.6 |
50.8 |
Indonesia |
3.8 |
6.0 |
7.2 |
15.5 |
India |
5.9 |
8.4 |
11.7 |
25.2 |
South
Korea |
15.7 |
21.6 |
25.6 |
48.0 |
Malaysia |
5.8 |
6.3 |
9.1 |
13.7 |
Singapore |
11.8 |
16.9 |
26.0 |
40.8 |
Thailand |
9.8 |
12.6 |
14.5 |
35.1 |
|
US |
|
2005-Q4 |
2007-Q1 |
2009-Q1 |
2012-Q1 |
China |
9.8 |
21.7 |
51.6 |
76.9 |
Hong
Kong |
22.6 |
21.3 |
29.2 |
47.6 |
Indonesia |
2.8 |
4.9 |
5.9 |
12.7 |
India |
20.5 |
36.4 |
40.5 |
72.0 |
South
Korea |
54.6 |
71.5 |
72.4 |
94.7 |
Malaysia |
9.9 |
13.1 |
13.1 |
20.2 |
Singapore |
20.5 |
24.8 |
30.6 |
64.0 |
Thailand |
3.5 |
6.1 |
6.6 |
12.3 |
Table 1 >>
(Click to Enlarge)
A
second element of commonality in these countries appears
to be a growth process associated with a large expansion
of bank credit. Bank credit growth has overshot GDP
growth in almost all countries, resulting in a sharp
increase in the bank credit to GDP ratio (Chart 1).
As is well known, banks, given their dependence on deposits
for their capital, would prefer to avoid exposure to
illiquid assets with lower resale value such as industrial
capital equipment, because it would expose them to the
risks associated with liquidity mismatches. The net
result has been a substantial increase in credit to
the household sector or in retail credit/personal loans
for housing, for purchases of automobiles and durables
and for consumption. According to estimates relating
to the middle of the last decade: ''Of the domestic credit
that banks have extended to private borrowers, a growing
share has gone to consumers. In 2004, consumer lending
accounted for 53 per cent of total bank lending in Malaysia,
49 per cent in Korea, 30 per cent in Indonesia, 17 per
cent in Thailand, 15 per cent in China, and 10 per cent
in the Philippines.'' Even in countries where the estimates
suggest that retail lending is low, such as China and
Thailand, this is because banks that do not lend directly
to the household sector often do so indirectly. They
provide credit to a second tier of intermediaries, often
in the informal financial sector, which in turn lend
to households. While a large proportion of these loans
is for housing, other loans such as for purchases of
automobiles or to finance credit-card receivables have
also increased considerably. The focus seems to be on
lending short term or against assets considered more
liquid.
Chart
1 >>
(Click to Enlarge)
The third common feature in the evolution of Asian
financial structures is the kind of financial diversification
visible in these economies. Given the huge increase
in banks' claims on other sectors of the economy,
the financial transformation of Asia has not been
accompanied by a reduction in the importance of banks
in the financial sector. Rather banks still account
for a substantial share of assets resting in the financial
sector. Yet the evidence of a growing role for stock
and bond markets and insurance companies, mutual funds
and pension funds is overwhelming. But the nature
of this presence needs examination.
Consider, to start with, the stock markets in these
countries. An index like the ratio of market capitalization
to GDP (Chart 2), to a much greater extent than the
number of listed companies or the volume of trading,
points to a huge increase in the size of these markets.
However, much of this is a result of the inflation
in stock prices that has resulted from trading in
the secondary market. The IPO market (or the role
of the stock market as a source of capital to finance
corporate investment) is still limited and highly
volatile in terms of volumes mobilised. Asset price
inflation occurs partly because of the inflow of foreign
capital and domestic surpluses into the secondary
market which is both narrow (in terms of the number
of companies whose shares are listed and actively
traded) and shallow (in terms of the number of shares
of these companies available for trading after taking
account of the holdings of promoters and long-term
investors). In sum, though the stock market seems
present and growing in size and visibility, it is
as yet not an important agent from the point of view
of making finance a supply-side spur to corporate
investment.
Chart
2 >>
(Click to Enlarge)
Interestingly, the development of the bond market
too remains limited and highly uneven across the region
(Table 2). It is only in South Korea that the corporate
local currency bond market exceeds the government
bond market in size. Moreover, even where bond markets
are developed, government securities seem to account
for a significant share of all securities issued in
the domestic market. There are differences in the
relative shares of the corporate bond market in the
incremental growth of these markets; but just as banking
dominates the financial sector, government securities
still dominate bond markets in most contexts. This
is of significance given the trend towards reining
in government borrowing not just from central banks
but also from the open market. Unless counterbalanced
by the growth of the corporate bond market, this could
see some shrinking in the relative importance of bond
markets in these countries.
As for other segments of the financial sector such
as insurance companies, pension funds and mutual funds,
growth is driven largely by three factors. One is
the lack in many of these countries of an extensive
system of social security, necessitating investment
in insurance or financial assets to provide for contingencies
and retirement. The second is the growing privatisation
of parts of even the limited insurance and pension
system, encouraging entry of a new set of private
institutions, including foreign ones. And the third
is the lack of adequate savings options for sections
of the middle class emerging from the process of rising
per capita incomes. They then turn to investments
in mutual funds as a means to invest small sums in
equity or debt markets. However, the resources mobilised
in these sectors too are not percolating into the
productive sectors.
Table
2: Size of LCY Bond Market in % GDP
(Local Sources) |
|
Ratio
of government local currency bonds to GDP (%) |
|
Ratio
of corporate local currency bonds in GDP (%) |
|
|
CN |
HK |
ID |
KR |
MY |
SG |
TH |
CN |
HK |
ID |
KR |
MY |
SG |
TH |
Dec-95 |
|
5.3 |
12.6 |
15 |
6.9 |
|
|
|
12.6 |
0 |
8.9 |
0.5 |
|
|
Dec-00 |
16.6 |
8.2 |
35.4 |
25.7 |
38 |
26.6 |
22.8 |
0.3 |
27.6 |
1.4 |
48.8 |
35.2 |
20.9 |
4.5 |
Dec-05 |
36.4 |
9.2 |
17.1 |
45.9 |
42.6 |
37.4 |
37.6 |
2.8 |
38.8 |
2.1 |
42.1 |
31.7 |
28.8 |
8.1 |
Dec-11 |
33.9 |
37.1 |
11.4 |
47.5 |
56.6 |
47 |
54.5 |
11.4 |
31.9 |
2 |
67 |
38 |
28.2 |
13 |
Table 2 >>
(Click to Enlarge)
Finally, a fourth common feature, but one that is uneven
in evolution across countries is the increase in securitisation
and the growth of derivatives markets. Given the substantial
increase in bank credit and its role in financing a
segmented and diverse retail market, banks would want
to transfer risk for a fee. To do that they need to
create low risk securities by combining assets from
different markets, geographies and income groups. Once
the securitisation process begins, the distance to complex
derivatives is short, and there is a replication of
the market for complex and opaque assets in Asian developing
countries as well.
The implications of these features of the evolution
of Asian finance need emphasising. The functional school
of finance and the votaries of financial liberalisation
it has spawned make a case for financial diversification,
financial deepening (with a higher ratio of financial
assets to GDP), and increased financial intermediation
on the grounds that it facilitates the process of intermediation
between savers and investors and does so in the most
''efficient'' way possible. This suggests that finance
is an instrument facilitating investment from the supply
side by mobilising capital and channelling it to the
high return projects that might otherwise be deprived
of needed support.
However, as noted above, the recent Asian experience
would suggest that financial proliferation largely facilitates
new lines of business in financial services and affects
the real economy more from the demand side through the
debt-financed household expenditure it promotes. One
consequence is that excessive exposure to retail markets
becomes a source of fragility in these countries just
as it did in the developed countries.
As compared to this it was during the years of regulation
and so-called ''financial repression'' with its development
banks, directed credit programmes and differential interest
rates, that efforts were made to channel finance into
productive activities, including in sectors like agriculture
that would have been otherwise deprived of credit at
reasonable interest rates. During those years finance
was important as a supply side facilitator of investment,
but the proliferation of financial markets, institutions
and instruments was limited. That did not, however,
limit but rather helped the financing of the real economy.
*
This article was originally published in the Business
Line on 3 September 2012. |
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|