But there was more to come. The next setback
to the regulatory framework was a result of the way
the TRAI went about its task of fixing tariffs. In its
first consultation paper on Telecom Tariffs issued in
November 1997, the TRAI proposed that existing rentals
on basic or fixed line services should be increased
by 63 to 140 per cent for different categories of subscribers,
the number of free call units allowed during a bimonthly
billing cycle should be reduced from 250 in rural areas
and 150 in urban areas to 120 and that a uniform charge
of Rs. 1,30 per extra call should be insttuted in lieu
of the existing sliding scale in which call rates increase
from Rs. 0.60 to Rs. 0.80, Rs. 1.00, Rs. 1.25 and Rs.
1.40 as the number of calls made increase. In addition,
it proposed a reduction in long distance call charges
by upto 60 per cent.
It should be obvious that the intent of this exercise
was virtually to do away with two kinds of cross-subsidisation
considered acceptable in telecom pricing strategies:
first, the subsidisation of poorer, lower end users
who are to be attracted into the network by lower rentals
and lower call charges for less-intensive use; and,
second, cross-subsidisation of local traffic with revenues
from long distance traffic. While it is true that as
a network matures, an effort must be made to reduce
the extent of cross-subsidisation, it could not be claimed
on the basis of telephone and call densities that the
network in India
had reached that level of maturity. Nor was the extent
of reduction of cross subsidisation even in countries
like France as much had been proposed by the TRAI.
It is not surprising, therefore, that the proposal which would
have adversely affected low-end users and benefited
well-to-do business subscribers was seen as a way of
increasing the revenues of new private basic services
operators investing in local networks through an inequitous
rationalisation of the tariff structure. Despite calls
for a moderation in reduction of cross-subsidisation
from Parliamentarians, the TRAI chose early in 1999
to issue a note on the new tariffs and leaked to the
press the fact that it had issued such a notification.
This again resulted in an unnecessary brush with the
Communications Minister and Parliament, which was finally
resolved with a structure which reduced cross-subsidisation
to a lesser degree but still provided some "relief"
to new private operators and high-end users.
The TRAI's actions cannot even be defended on the grounds
that its tariff setting principles are scientific. This
comes through for example from an anlysis of its tariff
setting procedures for cellular operators. The basic
principle adopted by the TRAI is that rentals should
cover capital costs, while call charges should cover
operating costs. Our earlier discssion made clear that
this does not tally with any economic reasoning on how
a utility like telecom access should be priced given
its characteristics
But what is even more disturbing is the fact that when
calculating costs, there was no effort to make a normative
assessment of what such costs should be. Consider the
case of capital expenditures on cellular lines to be
recovered through the rental. Capital expenditures consists
of depreciation computed assuming a 10 year life span
of equipment and weighted average interest costs placed
as high as 20 per cent. Capital cost per subscriber
is computed after taking utilisation of equipment into
account. To make the calculation the TRAI seems to have
unquestioningly relied on estimates provided to it by
the cellular operators themselves. The absurdity of
this comes through when we look at how estimates of
capital expenditure per mobile line varied between circles
and metros and even across operators in metros (Table
5).
Table
5 >> Click
to Enlarge
To deal with variations between metros and circles the
TRAI decided to base their recommendations on the metro
calculations. But how is the variation within metros
to be dealt with ? The appropriate procedure would have
been to make a normative estimate of costs, which would
have brought the estimate closer to the lowest figure
in the set, since the nature of equipment used is more
or less the same. The use of mormative costing procedures
is routine in the case of organisations like the Bureau
of Industrial Costs and Prices. Rather than opt for
that procedure, what the TRAI did was to ignore the
abnoramally high maximal value and then take the median
value of the rest of the figures to arrive at the capital
cost with which rentals are to be computed when some
apropriate level of utilisation as been reached. This
procedure is clearly indefensible and would have inflated
capital costs as well as the derived rentals. It was
on this basis that the TRAI came to the abnormally high
rental figure of Rs. 400 to Rs. 484 per month, as compared
to the Rs. 156 which prevailed under the original tariff
structure.
The above instance is just quoted as an example to illustrate
how there is nothing scientific about what the TRAI
has done, making the debate between it, the government
and users a battle between those who want "economic"
costing and those who want subsidies, as it is often
presented to be. The problem with the regulation and
tariff setting framework which had the TRAI at the centre
was that there was no internal way to monitor the "monitor".
This is what explains the repeated recourse to the courts
and the periodic clash between the TRAI on the one hand
and the executive, the Parliament and the consumer on
the other.
The TRAI, of course, held that its procedures were correct
and that without hiking tariffs the process of introducing
competition in the telecom sector would be aborted.
If that is accepted, then the message which remains
is that from the point of view of society and the individual
consumer the price of competition is too high and therefore
liberalisation is not warranted.
|