On 30 August 2003, just
before the negotiating teams at the WTO in Geneva went back to their
respective countries to prepare for the Ministerial Meeting at Cancun, the
deadlock over intellectual property and public health was finally broken.
The TRIPs Council agreed on legal changes that are officially supposed to
make it easier for poorer countries to import cheaper generics made under
compulsory licensing if they are unable to manufacture the medicines
themselves.
The decision settled the one piece of unfinished business on intellectual
property and health that remained from the WTO Ministerial Conference in
Doha in November 2001, and which had been left hanging for the previous
months because of fierce resistance from the
US government and the multinational lobby.
The decision was
immediately hailed by some and described as a great victory for the
developing countries and indeed for the people of the world. ‘This is a
historic agreement for the WTO’, said the WTO Director-General Supachai
Panitchpakdi. ‘The final piece of the jigsaw has fallen into place,
allowing poorer countries to make full use of the flexibilities in the
WTO’s intellectual property rules in order to deal with the diseases that
ravage their people. It proves once and for all that the organization can
handle humanitarian as well as trade concerns.’
However, the actual details of the agreement suggest that such extravagant
and fulsome praise may be uncalled for. In fact, many independent
analysts, along with the NGOs and civil society groups that had been
fighting for an agreement on this issue, feel betrayed by the final
character of the resolution, and have argued that it will do little or
nothing to improve the situation for people in the developing countries in
terms of accessing cheaper life-saving drugs.
Thus, James Love of the Consumer Project on Technology has written that
‘the persons who have negotiated this agreement have given the world a new
model for explicitly endorsing protectionism.’ Oxfam and Medecin sans
Frontieres, two groups who have closely followed the negotiations, have
called the solution ‘unworkable’ saying that the ‘deal was designed to
offer comfort to the US and the western pharmaceutical industry’ and that
‘global patent rules will continue to drive up the price of medicines’.
It is even possible to argue that the final form of the resolution is
actually a step backward compared to the flexibilities that existed in the
original TRIPs agreement, and that the entrenched position of the large
international drug monopolies is further legalized by the recent
statement. However, to understand this, it is necessary to provide some
background on both the international pharmaceuticals industry, and the
TRIPs agreement and the controversies that have surrounded it.
Chart 1 >>
The International Pharma Industry
Pharmaceutical markets
differ from markets for most other commodities, since drugs are rather
special commodities. Private drug markets typically suffer from a number
of forms of market failure. These include: (a) informational
imbalances—thus, for example, consumers are not in a position to judge the
quality and efficacy of drugs, which creates the need for a social
monitoring and surveillance system; (b) monopoly and lack of competition
created by patent protection, brand loyalty and market segmentation; (c)
externalities in the form of social benefits of drug consumption. Drugs
play a significant social role in that they are an integral part of the
realization of the fundamental human right to health. For these reasons,
pharmaceutical products are classified as essential goods, with the
understanding that they have to be accessible to all people.
Obviously, access to the latest available technology in this sphere is
crucially important for the health and welfare of children, not only in
terms of availability to all children but also the access of mothers.
There is clear need for some social control over investment in technology
relating to drug production, and the subsequent prices and distribution,
not only because of the market failures described above, but also since
unregulated drug markets tend to create substantial inequity, particularly
in terms of access to drugs.
The world market for drugs is a huge one, but it is dominated by only
three countries—the
United States,
Japan and Germany—which account for more than two-thirds of total sales.
In fact, only 15 per cent of the world's population accounts for 86 per
cent of drug spending, while the remaining 85 per cent get only a 14 per
cent share.
The difficulty of ensuring even a minimum degree of democratic access to
life-saving drugs is compounded by the high degree of concentration in the
international drug industry. Table 1 describes the situation in 1998, when
the top ten companies controlled 36 per cent of the market and the top
twenty companies controlled 57 per cent of world sales.
Table 1 :
Top Ten
Pharma companies in 1998 |
Company |
Sales, US $ bn |
% of global sales |
% growth p.a. |
Novartis |
10.6 |
4.2 |
5 |
Merck |
10.6 |
4.2 |
8 |
Glaxo
Wellcome |
10.5 |
4.2 |
88 |
Pfizer |
9.9 |
3.9 |
21 |
Bristol
Myers Squibb |
9.8 |
3.9 |
11 |
Johnson & Johnson |
9.0 |
3.6 |
8 |
American
Home Products |
7.8 |
3.1 |
1 |
Roche |
7.6 |
3.0 |
6 |
Lily |
7.4 |
2.9 |
17 |
Smith Kline Beecham |
7.3 |
2.9 |
6 |
Leading 10 companies |
90.5 |
35.9 |
8 |
Leading 20 companies |
143.8 |
57.2 |
9 |
|
Since then there have
been more mega-mergers which have made the industry even more
concentrated. Glaxo Wellcome merged with SmithKline Beecham, Pfizer merged
with Warner Lambert, and the companies Hoechst-Marion, Merrell and Rhone-Poulenc
merged to form Aventis. Currently the top ten companies are estimated to
control more than half of the world market, and the top twenty companies
more than two-thirds of the world market.
Apart from mergers, there is growing evidence that drug companies are
using the patent system to establish monopoly control. Often patents are
filed for products or chemical substances, or now even genes, whose
attributes are not fully known, simply to pre-empt the competition and
allow for monopoly rents once further research—possibly by others
including public agencies—reveals the uses. As Table 2 shows, the top ten
filers of patents include six drug companies and two companies
specializing in genetic research.
Such monopoly allows drug companies to charge prices
that are as high as they feel the market will bear, without reference to
or well in excess of the actual costs of R&D that they may have borne.
Thus there is wide variation in prices of the same drug charged not only
by different companies but even by the same company in different markets.
As Charts 2a, 2b and 2c, show, the prices
of branded or patented products are often far higher than the prices of
similar medicines produced by alternative or generic sources.
Chart 2a >>
Chart 2b >>
Chart 2c >>